Chap. 6b: Wages, Rent, Profits

The Three Sources of Revenue From the Parts of Price

15 In the most improved societies, there are a few commodities with prices made up only of wages and profits.

  • There are even fewer commodities with their price made up only of wages.
  • For example, the price saltwater fish has:
    • the wages of the fisherman
    • the profits of the capital employed in fishery
      • Rent makes a part of it only sometimes.
  • On the other hand, the price of a salmon freshwater fish pays for river rent, wares, and profit.
  • Poor people in Scotland gather Scotch pebbles from the seashore and sell them to the stone cutter.
    • The price they get represents their wages.

16 The price of any commodity must have one, some, or all of those three parts.

  • Whatever remains after paying the rent and wages for the end product must be profit to somebody.

17 Since all commodities have these components, the whole produce of a society, taken complexly, must also resolve itself into the same three parts to be distributed among some its members as the:

  • wages of their labour
  • profits of their stock
  • rent of their land

Wages, profit, and rent, are the three original sources of all revenue and all exchangeable value.

  • All other revenue is ultimately derived from some one or other of these.

18 Wages are the revenue from labour.

  • Profits are the revenue derived from stock by the person who manages or employs it.
  • Interest is revenue derived from stock lent to another as money.
    • It is the compensation which the borrower pays to the lender for the profit he can make from using that money.
      • Part of that profit naturally belongs to the borrower.
        • He runs the risk and takes the trouble of employing it.
      • Part of that profit belongs to the lender.
        • He gives the borrower the opportunity of making this profit.
    • Interest is always a derivative revenue.
      • It is made up of profit gained from the use of the money.
      • If it does not earn a profit, it must earn a revenue from other sources, unless the borrower is a spendthrift who contracts a second debt to pay the interest of the first debt.
  • Rent is the revenue from land and belongs to the landlord.
  • The farmer’s revenue is derived partly from his labour and partly from his stock.
    • Land to him is only the instrument which enables his wages and profits.
  • All taxes and all revenue founded on taxes, such as salaries, pensions, and annuities, are derived from wages, profits, or rent.

19 When wages, rent, and profits belong to different persons, they are readily distinguished

  • But when they belong to different persons, they are sometimes confounded with one another.

20 Farmers who farm their own land, like the North American and West Indian planters, should earn both profits and rent by themselves.

  • They frequently confound rents with profits.
    • We seldom hear the rent of a plantation, but frequently of its profit.

21 Common farmers frequently work directly on the farms they manage.

  • They seldom employ an overseer to manage their farms.
  • After paying the rent, they should have enough crop remaining to:
    • replace the stock employed, with ordinary profits
    • serve as his wages both as farm worker and overseer
      • In this case, his wages are mixed into his ordinary profits.

22 An independent manufacturer who works his own stock gains both wages and profits.

  • In this case, his wages are also mixed into his profits.

23 A gardener who cultivates his own garden combines the character of the landlord, farmer, and labourer.

  • His produce, therefore, should pay him rent, profit, and wages.
  • In this case, his rent and profit revenues are mixed into his wages.

24 The price of most commodities in civilized countries are made up largely of rent and profits, instead of wages.

  • Thus, the annual produce of a country’s labour will always be sufficient to command much more labour than what was used to create that produce.
  • If the country employed all the labour it could annually purchase, the quantity of labour would increase greatly every year.
    • The produce of every succeeding year would have vastly greater value than the year before.
    • However, the idle people of every country consume much of it.
  • The value of a country’s produce will depend annually on how it is divided between the idle and the industrious.

Next: Book 1, Chapter 7A: Natural and Market Price

Words: 719

Leave a Reply

Fill in your details below or click an icon to log in:

WordPress.com Logo

You are commenting using your WordPress.com account. Log Out / Change )

Twitter picture

You are commenting using your Twitter account. Log Out / Change )

Facebook photo

You are commenting using your Facebook account. Log Out / Change )

Google+ photo

You are commenting using your Google+ account. Log Out / Change )

Connecting to %s